The Buzz

The F-35: Who Should Own the Rights to the Software Inside?

Who owns the intellectual property rights to weapon systems? Who should? In a notable essay in Foreign Affairs on “The End of the Military Industrial Complex,” former Deputy Defense Secretary Bill Lynn once wrote of how “a number of software developers have refused defense work because they fear they would have to relinquish the intellectual property rights to whatever they produce.” The fix was straightforward, he asserted: “the Pentagon can attract companies such as Google [in part] by loosening its stringent intellectual property rules”. This week, Lieutenant General Chris Bogdan, head of the Joint Strike Fighter program, says that he is “playing catch-up now every which way I turn when it comes to intellectual property rights”. On Defense-Aerospace.com, Giovanni de Briganti predictably called this yet another reason never to buy F-35s. So what’s the real story? Unfortunately for anyone who would like to pillory either government or industry, the answer is not so simple.

The issue is longstanding. As Sandra Erwin reported for National Defense magazine, back in 2001, when the JSF program office was standing up, “little thought was given to who legally owned the rights to the technical data and intellectual property associated with the aircraft.” In 2007, the John Warner National Defense Authorization Act called for more attention, mandating that the managers of major defense programs establish “acquisition strategies that provide for technical data rights needed to sustain such systems and subsystems over their life cycle.” In 2010, making better decisions about intellectual property rights would be a major thrust of then-Under Secretary of Defense Ash Carter's original Better Buying Power (BBP) initiative. What came next were over enthusiastic efforts by not a few program managers unschooled in basic economics. In that first year, one supplier to the Pentagon requested my help in explaining to his customer why he couldn’t get the design rights for free after paying for the kit and the drawings. The underlying technology had been developed at the company’s expense—not the government’s, at least in that case—and letting go could create future competitors.

Now-Under Secretary Frank Kendall subsequent revision of the guidance (BBP 2.0) contained more nuanced language. By Valerie Insinna and Aaron Mehta's recounting in Defense News this week, the issue of intellectual property was seemingly not on his list of concerns with the F-35 for the next administration. His purview, however, is at a higher level, and technical data rights always seem a little arcane. As I wrote in “Better Buying Power or Better Off Not? Purchasing Technical Data for Weapon Systems” (Defense Acquisition Research Journal, July 2014, pp. 694–714), the details are sufficiently bedeviling that program managers can readily get the decision wrong in either direction. I covered this question here in an earlier essay, “Better Buying Power at Work: Technical Data for the Joint Light Tactical Vehicle,” in February 2014, but I repeat the point, as the issues seem evergreen:

 this work is no easy task. Neither the government nor its potential suppliers can be certain of future costs and prices, as every actor in the system is planning, bidding, or negotiating with imperfect information about advanced technologies. The program manager will have broad technical knowledge of armored vehicles, and the should-cost analysis that BBP directs, but he is not a production manager with a first-hand understanding of contractors’ costs. Whoever is chosen as the original source will know his own production capabilities reasonably well, but much less about a competitor's costs. That potential second source will similarly understand his own production capabilities, but he will lack the tacit knowledge amassed during the development of the system.

With all that uncertainty, the program manager could easily pay too much now for rights that do not lead to lower future prices. Alternatively, he could easily bid too low now, and thus fail to secure a deal for rights that would have led to displacement of the first-tranche winner at a lower second-tranche price. The economics that such a manager must master are hardly basic. So are there any rules of thumb that might help?

Pages