Donald Trump's Real Fear: Are Immigrants Really Making America More Progressive?
With some exceptions, people tend to choose a political party first and then change their opinions to match that party’s platform.
Economists Paolo Giuliano and Marco Tabellini wrote new working paper titled “The Seeds of Ideology: Historical Immigration and Political Preferences in the United States.” Helen Andrews at the American Conservative summarizes the paper here with a blog titled: “How Early Immigration Shifted Our Politics Permanently To The Left.” The paper’s authors use a shift-share instrument to see how European immigrants in the early 20th century affected public support for the Democratic Party and redistribution on the county level during the 2006-2018 period. They found that more European immigrants in the past led to more support for the Democratic Party and for redistribution on the country level today.
This new working paper complements Tabellini’s earlier paper in the Review of Economic Studies where he found that European immigrant populations on the city level, especially if they were from Eastern and Southern Europe, resulted in lower municipal tax rates, less tax revenue, and less government supply of services during the 1910 to 1930 period. According to this earlier paper, a one-standard deviation increase in the immigrant population (about five percentage points) reduced per capita government spending by 5 percent and property tax rates by 7.5 percent on the city level. This is especially important back then because most government services were supplied locally.
Looking at the papers together presents the full picture. Giuliano and Tabellini wrote:
While there is no statistically significant relationship between the 1910-1930 fraction of immigrants and the Democratic vote share until 1924 (included), the coefficient abruptly spikes in 1928, when it becomes strongly positive and highly statistically significant.
We posit that 1928 was the first national election when immigrant-heavy counties swung to support Democrats because it was the first national election after the National Origins Quota Act permanently cut legal immigration from Europe (the Emergency Quota Act of 1921 limited immigration, but many thought it was a temporary post-war emergency measure). Closing the border removed the politically-effective counter-argument that more welfare would attract immigrants who will take advantage of new government programs. Closing the border thus freed both natives and immigrants to vote for more welfare without the fear that immigrants would come from Europe to consume the new benefits. A relatively open immigration system reduced support for redistribution and big government, but the removal of that political check resulted in increased public support for those programs.
Tabellini’s two papers are not contradictory, but the second seems like a very serious challenge to the research we’ve conducted on how immigrants don’t increase the size of government (not Tabellini’s goal, by the way). However, the two papers are perfectly consistent with the theory that Powell and Nowrasteh lay out in their forthcoming book: Government doesn’t grow as fast when the borders are open and government grows more when the borders are closed.
Many prominent economists who support more redistribution believe that such programs are only politically possible after the borders are closed. They have a lot of history on their side. The role of government in American domestic life surged only after Congress enacted the restrictive immigration laws of the 1920s. To be sure, the Great Depression and other ideological shifts in public opinion were necessary for big changes in American policy during the New Deal, but they were politically possible because closed immigration removed the politically-effective immigrant welfare-queen argument.
Prior to the closure of the border in the 1920s, American progressives and other supporters of a large welfare state near-uniformly supported restricting immigration because they saw it as a political impediment to their goals (and for other less-savory reasons like eugenics). Even Karl Marx, Friedrich Engels, and their American communist followers warned that immigrant-induced diversity reduced worker solidarity and that that would slow Marxist efforts to stoke a socialist revolution in the United States or achieve middle-ground policies like the creation of a large welfare state and mass unionization.[1] Across the developed world today, support for welfare, redistribution, and government provision of public goods is inversely correlated with the share of the population that is foreign-born and diverse. The early Marxists worry was well-founded.
There is a big difference between Tabellini’s papers that bears pointing out. Tabellini’s first paper looks at the effect of immigration on actual spending and taxation policies on the city level. His second paper looks at how immigrant populations in the past influenced public opinion decades later. That is an important difference. The decline in local government provision of services and rise of state and federal spending since the New Deal means that we can’t replicate Tabellini’s first paper today and get meaningful results. Looking at public opinion is worthwhile and interesting, but it’s a different measurement.
Below, we briefly look at the relationship between real federal outlays per capita and the immigrant share of the population at the national and state level. Although useful, looking at the national-level relationship can only tell us so much. In the next section, we look at the relationship between changes in real state-level outlays per capita and the immigrant share of the population to see if there is a relationship between growth in immigration and growth in government spending.
Real Federal Outlays Per Capita and Immigration
Figure 1 tracks real federal outlays as a percent of GDP and the immigrant share of the population. There is no statistically significant relationship between the variables, but the coefficient is negative. There simply isn’t a positive relationship between government outlays and immigration from 1928-2017. If one includes 1900-2017, the relationship becomes strongly and significantly negative whereby a 1 percent increase in the immigrant share of the population is correlated with a 1.3 percent decline in government spending as a share of GDP.
More importantly, what happened to federal outlays during the Golden Age of Immigration Restrictions? From 1921-1968, U.S. immigration law radically reduced annual inflows such that the percentage of the population that was foreign-born fell from 13 percent in 1920 to 4.8 percent in 1968 (Figure 2). The book end dates are the year of the enactment of the Emergency Quota Act of 1921 and the year the Immigration Act of 1965 went into effect. When immigration was most restricted, federal outlays as a percent of GDP increased from 6.9 percent to 18.9 percent, an increase of almost 174 percent. Congress created the New Deal and Great Society programs after the reduction in legal immigration caused the share of the foreign-born population to decline. In other words, the argument that immigrants would come in to take welfare benefits was not politically salient when the borders were closed. From 1968 to 2017, when immigration was slightly liberalized, federal outlays as a share of GDP rose from 18.9 percent to 20.4 percent, an increase of a mere 7.9 percent.
Real State Outlays Per Capita and Immigration
As mentioned above, it wouldn’t be useful to extend Tabellini’s earlier work on immigrants and city-level spending in the early 20th century to today because the state and federal governments supply goods that used to be supplied by cities. In the previous section, we looked at the correlation between federal spending as a percent of GDP and immigrant shares of the population. The national-level analysis is only suggestive because there is no United States with a different immigration policy that we can use for comparison. Thus, we turn to the relationship between changes in state-level spending and the immigrant population shares over time.
We look at state-level decadal panel data for state budgets and immigrant population shares over the period 1960-2010. Data on state government expenditures come from the Government Finance Database (GFD), which compiles government financial data collected by the U.S. Census Bureau and harmonizes the data for state, county, and local governments.[2] GFD data include detailed public financial data on revenues and expenditures broken down by type and function. Specifically, we focus on four variables of interest:
- General revenues: State revenues from all sources, including federal grants and any other intergovernmental revenue sources.
- General revenue from own sources: Revenues from state taxes, fees, returns on state-run insurance schemes, and revenues from state-owned/regulated enterprises like utilities and liquor stores.
- Total expenditures: All state expenditures such as wages, capital outlays, construction expenditures, and intergovernmental transfers.
- Direct expenditures: All state expenditures such as wages, capital outlays, and construction expenditures.
Using intercensal data, we convert the expenditures into per capita terms and adjust for inflation using the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index.[3] Data on the foreign-born share by state are taken from the 1960-2000 decennial Censuses and the 2008-2012 American Community Survey from IPUMS.[4] These data include the total population and foreign-born stock for each decade for each state for 1960-2012.[5]
Our objective is to test the correlation between changes in states’ foreign-born population and the growth in state government spending. Leveraging the panel structure of our data, we estimate fixed effects regressions that regress the log difference in per capita expenditures on the foreign-born share. In each model we control for state and region-by-year fixed effects. This implies that the correlation between spending and the foreign-born share is estimated from changes in the foreign-born shares within a state over time relative to other states in the same region and year.
Tabellini and others note that immigrant settlement patterns may reflect other local factors that are uncaptured by fixed effects. For instance, immigrants may settle in states that provide larger safety nets and that might appear to show that they grow the size of government while, in fact, they might just settle where it is already biggest. Similar to the approach used by Tabellini, we use a shift-share instrumental variable (IV) to partially address the endogeneity concerns.[6] In particular, we construct an instrument that apportions national immigrant inflows into the United States to states according to the shares that settled in each state in 1960 using this method.
Government Spending and Immigration, 1970-2010
Figure 3 shows the correlation between changes in real state-level per capita total expenditures and changes in the state-level foreign-born population share. Figure 4 shows the correlation between changes in real state-level per capita direct expenditures and changes in state-level foreign-born population share. Both figures show a negative correlation between expenditure growth and growth in the foreign-born share of the population.
To test whether these negative relationships are statistically significant, we run a series of fixed effects IV regressions. In each regression we instrument a state’s foreign-born share using a shift-share instrument and find negative correlations between state government spending growth and the foreign-born share (Table 1). The first column of Table 1 shows the first stage of our IV regressions. As a measure of our instrument’s strength we report a first stage F-statistic of 29.8, which is a strong instrument.[7] Columns 2 through 5 show correlations between state revenue growth, spending growth, and foreign-born shares.
The dependent variable in Columns 3 through 5 (Table 1) is the log difference of each per capita measure. The coefficient for each specification relates a percentage point increase in a state’s foreign-born share to a percentage change in the level of per capita revenues or expenditures. Our simple regressions show no significant correlation between both growth in general revenue and revenue from the state’s own sources, controlling for fixed effects. Only the estimate for total expenditure growth is significant at the 5 percent level. Column 4 shows a significant, negative correlation between a state’s foreign-born share and total government expenditure growth of about 1.3 percent. The estimate for direct expenditures in Column 5 is negative and only marginally significant.
Taken together, our regression results suggest that a larger share of immigrants at the state level is correlated with slower growth in state per-capita government expenditures. While these regressions attempt to control for endogeneity and other unobserved factors, the results are more suggestive than causal. Establishing a causal link between immigration and government spending or revenues would require additional empirical work outside of a blog post.
Conclusion
How immigrants affect the size and growth of government is a complex issue with many moving parts. Immigrants have tended to vote for the Democratic Party or its predecessor since the 1790s. When the Democratic Party was the laissez-faire party, immigrants voted for it. When it became the interventionist party, immigrants continued to vote for it. They did so because the Democratic Party has been more pro-immigration than its competitors during most of American history.
With some exceptions, people tend to choose a political party first and then change their opinions to match that party’s platform. Public opinion certainly has a huge influence on public policy as our system is designed to turn voter preference into policies, but the empirical work above indicates that more immigration is not related to growth in the size of state governments. The reactions of native-born voters to immigrants complicate the story significantly as immigrants don’t merely shift the median voter by being present but also by influencing the opinions of natives on myriad policy issues. Much of the work on this topic shows no relationship or a negative relationship between the two.
[1] Marx, K. and Engels, F. (2010). Collected Works, Volume 43, Letters 1868-70. London: Lawrence and Wishart, 474-6; Marx, K. and Engels, F. (1971). Marx and Engels on the Irish Question. Moscow, 354.
[2] Pierson K., Hand M., and Thompson F. (2015). The Government Finance Database: A Common Resource for Quantitative Research in Public Financial Analysis. PLoS ONE doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0130119
[3] The first year of available for most states in the GFD is 1972. For simplicity, we backshift the 1972 data to represent 1970. Since the District of Columbia reports data directly for 1970, we use the provided 1970 data.
[4] Steven Ruggles, Sarah Flood, Ronald Goeken, Josiah Grover, Erin Meyer, Jose Pacas and Matthew Sobek. IPUMS USA: Version 10.0 [dataset]. Minneapolis, MN: IPUMS, 2020. https://doi.org/10.18128/D010.V10.0
[5] We pool the 2008-2012 ACS 5-year estimates for the year 2010.
[6] See Card (2001) or Tabellini (2020) among others.
[7] This F-statistic is the Kleibergen-Paap F-statistic, which adjusts for clustering. A value higher than 16.4 implies a relatively strong instrument according to the Stock and Yogo (2005) critical values.
This article by Alex Nowrasteh and Andrew C. Forrester first appeared at the Cato Institute.
Image: Reuters.